If current events continue as presently trajected we are likely to see a slew of professional (and D1 college) athletic games played in "empty" stadiums for some unknown period of time. For gamblers (and fans), one immediate question is how playing in an empty stadium may impact the outcome. One piece of emerging conventional wisdom--fueled by little more than intuition--is that the putative "home field advantage" attributable to (assumed) systematic referee "bias" favoring home teams may vanish in empty stadiums.
It turns out that the "empty" stadium "experiment" has happened before--in Italian professional soccer flowing from a tragic soccer "hooligan" incident in 2007. Consequently, some data--albeit limited--exist. Perhaps unsurprisingly, two economists, Per Pettersson-Lidbom (Stockholm Univ.) and Mikael Priks' (CESifo, Germany), exploited these data, construed the temporary "empty stadium" policy as an exogenous shock to the number of spectators, and leveraged it to test the "referees may be biased due to social pressure" hypothesis.
Findings from their 2010 paper, Behavior under social pressure: Empty Italian stadiums and referee bias, generally comport with the received wisdom. Specifically, and as summarized in a recent Sports Illustrated article (here), in "full" stadiums home teams won the majority of matches. And they did so, in part, because the home teams received fewer red cards and yellow cards, and fewer penalty and foul calls. As well, when home teams were trailing, they received more injury time, the minutes that officials discretionarily tack onto the end of games, increasing their odds of catching up. When home teams were leading, injury time dwindled." However, for games played in "empty" stadiums the home team advantage effectively vanished and teams didn’t win at home any more than on the road. Contributing to this was that when no fans were in the stands the "home/away penalty differential shriveled. The favorable calls conferred on the home team dropped by 23%–70%, depending on the type of calls. Subjective close calls no longer favored the home team. Injury time favoring the home team declined as well."
While it remains difficult to conclusively rule out concurrent effects of an "empty" stadium on the athletes, the paper addresses such confounds to the extent that their research design allows. To be clear, however, the paper focuses on observing "the same referees overseeing the same two teams in the same stadium" and notes that they "behaved dramatically differently when spectators were present, versus when no one was watching." On the interpretative front the authors are generous to the referees: "It is not because officials are biased, much less because they are corrupt. It is because they are human. As such, they are susceptible to the powerful force that is social influence."
Recent Comments